A question which has occurred to me lately revolves around the oft-heard objection that, "Nuclear has always been a state enterprise." In other words, the high up-front capital cost (and attendant front-loaded risk from construction delays and potential intervenors) makes nuclear a tough pill to swallow for liberalized energy markets, despite the extremely low operating costs (and hence, low back-end risk).
This problem seems to extend well beyond nuclear energy itself; rather, it would seem to indict any capital-intensive energy projects where a given rate of return on investment is not guaranteed. It provokes the question - in a completely free market for electricity (as opposed to the admixture we have now), what would energy investment look like?
Some of the imbalance which currently exists now owes to the imbalance of externalities captured by the current regulatory environment. Sources like coal - especially older, "grandfathered" plants, are allowed to treat the atmosphere effectively as an open cesspool; at the other extreme, nuclear is expected to account (and pay for!) each last curie of waste produced, going as far as to return the site to greenfield status once the plant has closed. Meanwhile, indictment of nuclear as uniquely a "state industry" by its detractors rings somewhat hollow, given that yet more expensive, diffuse, and less reliable sources such as wind and solar would almost certainly be pushed to the margin under the same standard.
Obviously, a balance to the regulatory playing field is called for (although don't hold your breath waiting for that one…). Yet going a step further, assuming this, what would energy investment look like in a completely liberalized energy market?
Essentially, what such a market would appear to produce, if the current trend is any example, is likely sources in which costs are easily externalized to others (e.g. coal and to a lesser degree natural gas) or the costs are relatively distributed throughout the lifecycle (e.g., natural gas, where costs are largely on the fuel cost). Yet one predictable consequence of this - beyond the environmental impact - would be the impact on retail electricity price volatility. Again - natural gas is far from being historically "stable" in price.
Where does this leave nuclear? Ultimately, nuclear would seem to have the ability to moderate these types of price shocks, namely by providing stable, low-cost baseload power. This ultimately is where I believe technologies such as small modular reactors (SMRs) are so vital to the future of nuclear; they provide at least some means of blunting the capital risk of nuclear in liberalized energy markets. Further, incentives clearly matter - Pigouvian measures such as a carbon tax would go a long way toward leveling the playing field (again, don't hold your breath on this one.)
Yet even beyond this however, the need for innovative mechanisms for financing large, capital-intensive energy projects remains clear. Ultimately, my expertise is in nuclear technology and not finance, and thus I am at a loss for ideas. Given my own personal predilections toward free markets, it is often disappointing to see many market-oriented advocates simply put down nuclear as "socialist" rather than seeking out new vehicles and mechanisms to finance such projects through private investment. (Unlike many nuclear advocates such as Rod Adams, I do not share their antagonism to Wall Street, recognizing that ultimately private capital will be essential for future energy projects, especially as America's own government contemplates austerity measures in light of a growing entitlement crisis brought about by massive demographic shifts). One notable example of innovative ideas for finance comes from this excellent guest post at Idaho Samizdat, taking a lesson from the Dutch nutmeg trade. But further such ideas for innovative financing models are badly needed.
An alternative proposal is for legislative mandates such as portfolio standards - e.g., a "clean energy standard" similar to renewable energy portfolio standards which currently exist, mandating that utilities generate a certain fraction of their energy from designated sources. Beyond the obvious potential for peril of political manipulations on defining just what qualifies as "clean" (or attempts to game the standard by powerful, entrenched interests), this does nothing to solve the existing problems of financing which have ultimately precipitated the perceived need for such mandates.
Ultimately, this question goes well beyond nuclear; given the fact that liberalization in energy markets is unlikely to reverse course in the forseeable term, how can we develop new mechanisms to provide financing to capital-intensive (but lower long-term financial risk) projects, sans government intervention? This is the true long-term challenge, incumbent advocates of clean energy of all types as well as market advocates themselves. These kinds of questions are the kind whicn should form the basis of free market environmentalism (a term which need not be an oxymoron).
Unfortunately, these are questions I am ill-equipped to answer, yet they are (in my mind) vital to the future of energy markets.
This problem seems to extend well beyond nuclear energy itself; rather, it would seem to indict any capital-intensive energy projects where a given rate of return on investment is not guaranteed. It provokes the question - in a completely free market for electricity (as opposed to the admixture we have now), what would energy investment look like?
Some of the imbalance which currently exists now owes to the imbalance of externalities captured by the current regulatory environment. Sources like coal - especially older, "grandfathered" plants, are allowed to treat the atmosphere effectively as an open cesspool; at the other extreme, nuclear is expected to account (and pay for!) each last curie of waste produced, going as far as to return the site to greenfield status once the plant has closed. Meanwhile, indictment of nuclear as uniquely a "state industry" by its detractors rings somewhat hollow, given that yet more expensive, diffuse, and less reliable sources such as wind and solar would almost certainly be pushed to the margin under the same standard.
Obviously, a balance to the regulatory playing field is called for (although don't hold your breath waiting for that one…). Yet going a step further, assuming this, what would energy investment look like in a completely liberalized energy market?
U.S. natural gas prices, per EIA |
Where does this leave nuclear? Ultimately, nuclear would seem to have the ability to moderate these types of price shocks, namely by providing stable, low-cost baseload power. This ultimately is where I believe technologies such as small modular reactors (SMRs) are so vital to the future of nuclear; they provide at least some means of blunting the capital risk of nuclear in liberalized energy markets. Further, incentives clearly matter - Pigouvian measures such as a carbon tax would go a long way toward leveling the playing field (again, don't hold your breath on this one.)
Yet even beyond this however, the need for innovative mechanisms for financing large, capital-intensive energy projects remains clear. Ultimately, my expertise is in nuclear technology and not finance, and thus I am at a loss for ideas. Given my own personal predilections toward free markets, it is often disappointing to see many market-oriented advocates simply put down nuclear as "socialist" rather than seeking out new vehicles and mechanisms to finance such projects through private investment. (Unlike many nuclear advocates such as Rod Adams, I do not share their antagonism to Wall Street, recognizing that ultimately private capital will be essential for future energy projects, especially as America's own government contemplates austerity measures in light of a growing entitlement crisis brought about by massive demographic shifts). One notable example of innovative ideas for finance comes from this excellent guest post at Idaho Samizdat, taking a lesson from the Dutch nutmeg trade. But further such ideas for innovative financing models are badly needed.
An alternative proposal is for legislative mandates such as portfolio standards - e.g., a "clean energy standard" similar to renewable energy portfolio standards which currently exist, mandating that utilities generate a certain fraction of their energy from designated sources. Beyond the obvious potential for peril of political manipulations on defining just what qualifies as "clean" (or attempts to game the standard by powerful, entrenched interests), this does nothing to solve the existing problems of financing which have ultimately precipitated the perceived need for such mandates.
Ultimately, this question goes well beyond nuclear; given the fact that liberalization in energy markets is unlikely to reverse course in the forseeable term, how can we develop new mechanisms to provide financing to capital-intensive (but lower long-term financial risk) projects, sans government intervention? This is the true long-term challenge, incumbent advocates of clean energy of all types as well as market advocates themselves. These kinds of questions are the kind whicn should form the basis of free market environmentalism (a term which need not be an oxymoron).
Unfortunately, these are questions I am ill-equipped to answer, yet they are (in my mind) vital to the future of energy markets.
These are some interesting thoughts, and I'm afraid my expertise is also far from finance (but I'll throw my two-cents in anyway). I certainly agree that SMRs are an attractive option for financing purposes (for both domestic and export deployment), and I would add to the discussion the economic benefits of maintaining the current fleet of operating LWRs (so-called Light Water Reactor Sustainability [LWRS] or Life Beyond 60 [LB60] or a variety of other acronyms). If the existing fleet is decommissioned at the end of current licenses (either 40 or 60 years, depending on extensions), the resulting energy deficit would challenge our power grid and economy, as well as construction, manufacturing, and technological infrastructures. Work is being done in this area, but not nearly quickly enough.
ReplyDeleteThe idea of a clean energy standard is an interesting one, but the definition of clean energy would have to be deliberate. TVA offers its customers the option to buy "green" energy for an additional charge, but this includes only solar, wind, and hydro (I suppose the rational is that TVA's hydro-plants had the majority of their environmental impact decades ago ..). I remember a colloquium given by someone from TVA while I was at University of Tennessee, and someone asked about nuclear power being included in the "green" energy. The presenter said something sheepish and political, if memory serves. I think that most of the public does not include nuclear in clean energy sources, and this would have to be addressed if a clean energy standard were enforced.
@radioactivevegan: Excellent points all, particular your point about LWR life extensions - a key reason why I think projects like CASL are so important (namely in that they allow us to make the scientific and engineering case for broad life-extensions; looking at the energy deficit that emerges around 2020 or so is frankly scary enough to keep one awake at night).
DeleteYour experience with the TVA rep is telling, although not surprising - I'd almost expect a (non)-answer like that. It reminds me of the so-called "virtue funds" offered by investment companies - many of them explicitly exclude nuclear in their list of "vices" (along with alcohol, tobacco, guns, and others.) It sorely tempted me to invest in a corresponding "vice" fund (like VICEX) out of sheer spite alone. Of course, this is the problem, as you identify with "clean energy" portfolio standards - until nuclear is accepted into the fold of "politically correct" clean energy sources, trying to promote nuclear through such a tactic will be an uphill battle.